The Influence of Central Banks and Monetary Policies on the Trading Process

Best Binary Options Brokers 2020:
  • BINARIUM
    BINARIUM

    Top Broker!
    Best Choice For Beginners!
    Free Trading Education!
    Free Demo Account!
    Big Sign-up Bonus!

  • BINOMO
    BINOMO

    Perfect For Experienced Traders!

Instruments of Monetary Policy and its Objectives

There are number of instruments of monetary policy, which are important for business to understand, but, here it is also important to know what Monetary Policy is? Credit performs the important functions. Being the major part of the total supply of money in a modern economy, the value of money is influenced by the volume of credit. The volume of credit in the country is regulated for the economic stability. This regulation of credit by the central bank is known as “Monetary Policy”. It is also called Credit Control.

Monetary policy refers to the measure which the central bank of a country takes in controlling the money and credit supply in the country with a view to achieve certain specific economic objectives. It is also being defined as the regulation of cost and availability of money and credit in the economy.

Instruments of Monetary Policy

The instruments or methods of credit control or instruments of monetary policy are of two kinds:

  • Quantitative control
  • Qualitative control
  1. Quantitative Control

It seeks to control the total quantity of money and bank credit or to make the bank lend more or less. These are four ways of quantitative control.

  1. Credit Rationing
  2. Change in Reserve Ratio
  3. Open Market Operation
  4. Bank Rate policy
  • Bank Rate policy

The bank rate is the rate at which the central bank is willing to discount first class bill of exchange. Bank rate is different from “Market Rate”. Market rate is that rate of which the money market is willing to discount bill of exchange. Market rate is influenced by the banks rate. A rise in bank rate is generally followed by a rise in market rate and similarly, a fall or rise in the bank rate is followed by increase and decrease in the borrowing, and the volume of credit will be adjusted accordingly to the requirements of the market.

  • Open Market Operation

Open market operation is the most important instrument of monetary policy. It refers to purchase or sale of government securities, short term as well as long term, at the initiative of central bank, as a deliberate credit policy. These Bonds and securities are purchased or sold from or to the commercial banks and the general public in the country.

  • Change in Reserve Ratio

The commercial banks are required to keep a limited percentage of their deposits by law with the central bank. The central bank charges the ratio according to the need of controlling the credit. If the ration is raised, the cash available with the bank will be reduced, which will compel them to contract the volume of credit. Similarly when the ratio will be lowered, the credit power will expand.

  • Credit Rationing

This instrument of monetary policy is applied only in time of financial crises. The bank can collect by re-discounting bill of exchange, when credit is rationed by fixing the amount. This method of controlling credit can be justified only as a measure to meet exceptional emergencies, because it is open to serious abuses. There can be a danger, the rationing may not be satisfactory and the central bank may abuse the power by giving preferential treatment to favorite customers.

  1. Qualitative Control

It aims to influence the special type of credit, or to divert bank advances into certain channels, or to discourage from lending for certain purpose. These methods managing monitory policy are as below.

  1. Consumer Credit Rationing
  2. Moral Persuasion
  3. Direct Action
  • Consumer Credit Rationing

The consumer credit method of monetary management can be applied only when there is a rise of the scarcity of certain listed articles in the country. The central bank will impose specific restraints on consumer credit by raising the required down payments and shorting the maximum period of payment.

  • Moral Persuasion

The central bank of the country also implies a minor instrument of moral persuasion to influence the total borrowing at the central bank. Moral Persuasion, refer to the appeal to the commercial bank to act according to the directive of the central bank. The central bank may issue directives to commercial banks to follow the policies of the central bank.

Best Binary Options Brokers 2020:
  • BINARIUM
    BINARIUM

    Top Broker!
    Best Choice For Beginners!
    Free Trading Education!
    Free Demo Account!
    Big Sign-up Bonus!

  • BINOMO
    BINOMO

    Perfect For Experienced Traders!

  • Direct Action

Central bank may take direct action, if his policies are not followed by the commercial banks. Direct action involves direct dealings of central bank with the commercial banks. Direct action may be a refusal on the part of central bank to re-discount the bill of exchange or it may be in the shape of penalty rate of discounting for the banks not following the required policies.

Objectives of Monetary Policy

The main objectives of monetary policy are here below

  1. Stability of Internal Prices

Heavy fluctuation in the general price level is not good for an economy. They result in uncertainty, damaging production and un-employment. To ensure healthy growth of economy, stability in prices is advised through monetary policy

  1. Stability in Exchange Rate

Fluctuations in the external value of currency reduce the volume of foreign trade. So the stability in exchange rate is essential, and this objective is achieved by regulating the volume of currency to stabilize the rate of exchange.

  1. Full Employment

Another major objective of monetary policy is to achieve full employment of resources. Central bank adopts a suitable policy for this purpose.

  1. Economic Growth

In order to raise the living standard of people through higher production and general economic growth, the volume of credit is regulated for the proper supply of credit to the producers.

The influence of monetary policy on bank profitability

Author

Abstract

Suggested Citation

Download full text from publisher

Other versions of this item:

  • Claudio Borio & Leonardo Gambacorta & Boris Hofmann, 2020. ” The influence of monetary policy on bank profitability ,” International Finance, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 20(1), pages 48-63, March.

References listed on IDEAS

  1. Patrick Bolton & Xavier Freixas, 2006. ” Corporate Finance and the Monetary Transmission Mechanism ,” Review of Financial Studies, Society for Financial Studies, vol. 19(3), pages 829-870.

  • Patrick Bolton & Xavier Freixas, 2000. ” Corporate finance and the monetary transmission mechanism ,” Economics Working Papers 511, Department of Economics and Business, Universitat Pompeu Fabra.
  • Bolton, Patrick & Freixas, Xavier, 2001. ” Corporate Finance and the Monetary Transmission Mechanism ,” CEPR Discussion Papers 2892, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers.

  • Tobias Adrian & Hyun Song Shin, 2008. ” Liquidity and leverage ,” Staff Reports 328, Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

  • Altunbas, Yener & Gambacorta, Leonardo & Marqués-Ibáñez, David, 2007. ” Securitisation and the bank lending channel ,” Working Paper Series 838, European Central Bank.
  • Yener Altunbas & Leonardo Gambacorta & David Marques, 2008. ” Securitization and the bank lending channel ,” Proceedings 1101, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
  • Yener Altunbas & Leonardo Gambacorta & David Marqu�s, 2007. ” Securitisation and the bank lending channel ,” Temi di discussione (Economic working papers) 653, Bank of Italy, Economic Research and International Relations Area.

  • Leonardo Gambacorta & Simonetta Iannotti, 2005. ” Are there asymmetries in the response of bank interest rates monetary shocks? ,” Temi di discussione (Economic working papers) 566, Bank of Italy, Economic Research and International Relations Area.

  • M Arellano & O Bover, 1990. ” Another Look at the Instrumental Variable Estimation of Error-Components Models ,” CEP Discussion Papers dp0007, Centre for Economic Performance, LSE.

  • Demirguc-Kunt, Asli & Huizinga, Harry, 1998. ” Determinants of commercial bank interest margins and profitability : some international evidence ,” Policy Research Working Paper Series 1900, The World Bank.

  • Ugo Albertazzi & Leonardo Gambacorta, 2006. ” Bank Profitability and Taxation ,” Computing in Economics and Finance 2006 364, Society for Computational Economics.
  • Ugo Albertazzi & Leonardo Gambacorta, 2007. ” Bank profitability and taxation ,” Temi di discussione (Economic working papers) 649, Bank of Italy, Economic Research and International Relations Area.

  • Banerjee, Ryan & McLaren, Nick, 2020. ” Using changes in auction maturity sectors to help identify the impact of QE on gilt yields ,” Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Bank of England, vol. 52(2), pages 129-137.

  • Alessandri, Piergiorgio & Nelson, Benjamin, 2020. ” Simple banking: profitability and the yield curve ,” Bank of England working papers 452, Bank of England.
  • Piergiorgio Alessandri & Benjamin Nelson, 2020. ” Simple banking: profitability and the yield curve ,” Temi di discussione (Economic working papers) 945, Bank of Italy, Economic Research and International Relations Area.

  • Claudio Borio & Haibin Zhu, 2008. ” Capital regulation, risk-taking and monetary policy: a missing link in the transmission mechanism? ,” BIS Working Papers 268, Bank for International Settlements.

  • David Neumark & Steven A. Sharpe, 1989. ” Market structure and the nature of price rigidity: evidence from the market for consumer deposits ,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 52, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (U.S.), revised 1989.

  • Claudio Borio & Piti Disyatat, 2020. ” Unconventional Monetary Policies: An Appraisal ,” Manchester School, University of Manchester, vol. 78(s1), pages 53-89, September.

  • Claudio Borio & Piti Disyatat, 2009. ” Unconventional monetary policies: an appraisal ,” BIS Working Papers 292, Bank for International Settlements.
  • Claudio Borio & Anna Zabai, 2020. ” Unconventional monetary policies: a re-appraisal ,” BIS Working Papers 570, Bank for International Settlements.

  • Patrick McGuire & Goetz von Peter, 2009. ” The US dollar shortage in global banking and the international policy response ,” BIS Working Papers 291, Bank for International Settlements.

  • R Blundell & Steven Bond, “undated”. ” Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data model ,” Economics Papers W14&104., Economics Group, Nuffield College, University of Oxford.
  • Richard Blundell & Stephen Bond, 1995. ” Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models ,” IFS Working Papers W95/17, Institute for Fiscal Studies.
  • Blundell, R. & Bond, S., 1995. ” Initial Conditions and Moment Restrictions in Dynamic Panel Data Models ,” Economics Papers 104, Economics Group, Nuffield College, University of Oxford.

  • Yener Altunbas & Leonardo Gambacorta & David Marques-Ibanez, 2020. ” Does monetary policy affect bank risk? ,” Working Papers 12002, Bangor Business School, Prifysgol Bangor University (Cymru / Wales).

  • Ricardo J. Caballero & Takeo Hoshi & Anil K. Kashyap, 2006. ” Zombie Lending and Depressed Restructuring in Japan ,” NBER Working Papers 12129, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

  • Ugo Albertazzi & Leonardo Gambacorta, 2006. ” Bank profitability and the business cycle ,” Temi di discussione (Economic working papers) 601, Bank of Italy, Economic Research and International Relations Area.

  • Leonardo Gambacorta & David Marques-Ibanez, 2020. ” The bank lending channel: lessons from the crisis ,” BIS Working Papers 345, Bank for International Settlements.
  • Gambacorta, Leonardo & Marqués-Ibáñez, David, 2020. ” The bank lending channel: lessons from the crisis ,” Working Paper Series 1335, European Central Bank.

  • Gropp, Reint & Heider, Florian, 2009. ” The determinants of bank capital structure ,” Working Paper Series 1096, European Central Bank.

  • Morten Bech & Leonardo Gambacorta, 2020. ” Monetary policy in a downturn: Are financial crises special? ,” BIS Working Papers 388, Bank for International Settlements.

  • Maudos, Joaquin & Fernandez de Guevara, Juan, 2003. ” Factors Explaining the Interest Margin in the Banking Sectors of the European Union ,” MPRA Paper 15252, University Library of Munich, Germany.

  • Jeremy C. Stein, 1995. ” An Adverse Selection Model of Bank Asset and Liability Management with Implications for the Transmission of Monetary Policy ,” NBER Working Papers 5217, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

  • Raghuram G. Rajan, 2005. ” Has Financial Development Made the World Riskier? ,” Working Papers id:248, eSocialSciences.
  • Raghuram G. Rajan, 2005. ” Has Financial Development Made the World Riskier? ,” NBER Working Papers 11728, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

  • Benjamin M. Friedman & Kenneth N. Kuttner, 1993. ” Economic activity and the short-term credit markets: an analysis of prices and quantities ,” Working Paper Series, Macroeconomic Issues 93-17, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.

  • Buch, Claudia M. & Eickmeier, Sandra & Prieto, Esteban, 2020. ” Macroeconomic factors and micro-level bank risk ,” Discussion Paper Series 1: Economic Studies 2020,20, Deutsche Bundesbank.

  • Wilko Bolt & Leo de Haan & Marco Hoeberichts & Maarten van Oordt & Job Swank, 2020. ” Bank Profitability during Recessions ,” DNB Working Papers 251, Netherlands Central Bank, Research Department.

  • Tom Doan, “undated”. ” RATS program to replicate Arellano-Bond 1991 dynamic panel ,” Statistical Software Components RTZ00169, Boston College Department of Economics.

  • Beck, Thorsten & Levine, Ross & Loayza, Norman, 1999. ” Finance and the sources of growth ,” Policy Research Working Paper Series 2057, The World Bank.

  • Claudia M. Buch & Sandra Eickmeier & Esteban Prieto, 2020. ” Macroeconomic Factors and Micro-Level Bank Risk ,” CESifo Working Paper Series 3194, CESifo Group Munich.

More about this item

Keywords

NEP fields

Statistics

Corrections

All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item’s handle: RePEc:bis:biswps:514 . See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: (Christian Beslmeisl). General contact details of provider: http://edirc.repec.org/data/bisssch.html .

If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

If CitEc recognized a reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the “citations” tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

The Global Financial Crisis and The Role of Monetary Policy

Speech by Jürgen Stark, Member of the Executive Board of the ECB
at the 13th Annual Emerging Markets Conference 2020

Washington, 24 September 2020

Ladies and gentlemen, I am very pleased to address this distinguished audience.

Looking back over time, we see that the role and conduct of monetary policy has often changed in response to economic and financial crises. In fact, the international central banking community has always been eager to learn from past developments and experiences, also with respect to different experiences across countries. Of course, this does not imply that monetary policy in the past has always been the same everywhere. Certainly, differences exist in the way monetary policy is conducted across countries. But it is precisely because of the open-mindedness in discussing and the willingness to learn from each others’ experiences during the past century that monetary policy making went through an evolutionary process: an evolutionary process that improved the conduct of monetary policy over time and led to a great deal of convergence across countries.

Let me in my remarks briefly review this process. I will then discuss the specific lessons that we can learn from the recent episode of financial and economic turbulence, and conclude with the challenges ahead not only for monetary policy, but also for economic policies more generally.

It was in response to the major bank panics of the first half of the nineteenth century that the Bank of England adopted the “responsibility doctrine” proposed by Walter Bagehot. [1] This required the Bank to lend freely on the basis of any sound collateral, but at a penalty rate to prevent moral hazard. Half a century later, the Federal Reserve System was established in the United States in response to frequent banking crises, in particular the crisis of 1907, to serve as a lender of last resort similar to the Bank of England.

Under the gold standard gold convertibility served as the economy’s nominal anchor and was used as a way to ensure trust in a currency. Before the establishment of central banks, private banks and governments issuing banknotes had often overextended their gold reserves. In a sense, early central banks were strongly committed to price stability. However, from the 1920s onwards many central banks fell under public control. The Great Depression led to a major reaction against central banks, which were accused of exacerbating the crisis. In virtually every country, monetary policy was placed under the control of the Treasury and fiscal policy became dominant. In many countries, central banks followed a low interest rate policy to both stimulate the economy and to help the Treasury in marketing its debt.

In the 1950s independent monetary policy making by central banks was restored, and this was accompanied by a brief period of price stability until the mid 1960s. The belief that unemployment could be permanently reduced at the expense of higher inflation resulted in very accommodative monetary policy in the 1970s, which led to an increase in inflation as inflation expectations started to rise. Only a few countries, such as Germany, were an exception to this rule, as the Bundesbanks’s emphasis on monetary aggregates resulted in a much tighter monetary policy. By the end of the 1970s, central banks put renewed emphasis on credibility and started to tighten monetary policy so that inflation decreased significantly. In many countries central banks were granted independence and were given a mandate to keep inflation low. As a result, stable prices have become a fact of life for billions of people.

Today we are experiencing the worst economic and financial crisis of the post-war period. I am convinced that the knowledge gained as a result will again change and further sharpen the way we conduct monetary policy. So let me now share with you some thoughts on the direction in which I expect – and hope – monetary policy thinking to change in response to the current crisis.
The role of monetary policy and lessons from the financial crisis

I think it is fair to say that there was a widespread consensus over some key elements of the pre-crisis monetary policy paradigm. [2] In particular, against the background of the high inflation experience of the 1970s in many industrialised countries, the central bank consensus comprised three key elements:

Central bank independence as a corner stone for an effective monetary policy;

Price stability as the primary objective of central banks; and

Solidly anchored inflation expectations on the basis of transparent communication.

In addition, not least against the background of the “Great Moderation”, that is, the period of low inflation and macroeconomic stability in most industrialised countries which was observed during the 20 years before the crisis, the central bank consensus also emphasised three elements, to which the ECB has never subscribed. These are:

Monetary policy has a primary role in the management of aggregate demand in the short-run;

Money and credit indicators can be disregarded;

Monetary policy should react to asset price busts; not to asset price booms.

Let me discuss how I see these elements from today’s perspective, particularly in the context of the recent experience of the global financial and economic crisis, and draw conclusions with regard to the usefulness of these elements for the future conduct of monetary policy.

Let me start with my general conclusion: In my view, the first three elements have proven to be very valuable assets during the crisis and I view them as absolutely essential to the success of monetary policy. The latter three elements of this consensus should be seriously reconsidered. I think the crisis has made a convincing case for a more medium term orientation of monetary policy, which takes into account information in money and credit indicators, and which tries to lean against the wind as financial imbalances start to develop and pose risks to price stability in the medium term.

Let me now elaborate on the above elements and draw some conclusions:

Firstly, the crisis has – in my view – crucially underlined the importance of central bank independence as a corner stone of credible and effective monetary policy making. Of course, central bank independence is a precondition of effective monetary policy at all times. It is an important lesson which is not only evidenced by events in the history of central banking, but also by the academic literature, that any blurring of responsibilities can potentially lead to a loss of credibility for the central bank. Such a situation would ultimately undermine the effectiveness of monetary policy. [3] The effectiveness of monetary policy on the basis of institutional and operational independence was, however, fundamental during the crisis. During the turbulent market conditions that we experienced central banks had to implement extraordinary measures, both in terms of reducing policy rates to levels that are unprecedented, and in terms of unconventional liquidity measures. If these measures – untested as they are – are to be expected to exert any impact on economic decisions, they have to be seen by market participants as the result of an autonomous decision by the central bank. They have to be seen as consistent with its overall policy framework, rather than as the result of pressures from fiscal authorities. The reason is simple. If a central bank comes under pressure in times of crisis, and succumbs to that pressure, it is very unlikely to exit from such extraordinary measures in a timely manner. This may unanchor inflation expectations and thus undermine the effectiveness of the measures implemented during the crisis.

Secondly, regarding the objective of price stability and the anchoring of inflation expectations, the crisis taught us that well-anchored inflation expectations can act as an automatic stabiliser when uncertainty becomes destabilising. This is always true, in good times as well. In fact, well-anchored inflation expectations in the euro area were instrumental in avoiding large interest rate hikes before the crisis, when commodity prices rose sharply. At the height of the crisis, they became a policy instrument in their own right. Thanks to well-anchored inflation expectations we could avoid deflationary spirals and real interest rates could be reduced in tandem with nominal rates. It is noteworthy that if inflation expectations are well anchored, and are not affected by transient shocks to actual inflation, there is no need to manipulate monetary policy frameworks: there is no need to increase the inflation target as a means of resisting deflationary risks in times of macroeconomic distress. [4] Opportunistic manipulations of the monetary policy framework of course damage the foundations on which that framework rests. So, being able to rely on the stabilising effect of inflation expectations is clearly a preferable option.

Let me now turn to the elements of the consensus that are, from the perspective of the ECB, somewhat more controversial.

Firstly, the crisis has demonstrated that a monetary policy aimed at fine-tuning short-term objectives carries serious risks. Before the crisis, there was a widely-held conviction that monetary policy could focus more on short term demand management because inflation was firmly under control. Proponents of this view found support in the phenomenon of the “Great Moderation” observed in the twenty years before the crisis, a time of widespread macroeconomic stability and low inflation in most industrialised countries. Nonetheless, there were clear signs – and also warnings – that this short-term orientation could have negative side effects in the medium to long term. [5] As you know, these side effects manifested themselves in a spectacular build-up of monetary and financial imbalances. Although monetary policy frameworks oriented towards the medium term could probably not have completely prevented the current crisis, I am convinced that they would have helped to make it less disruptive.

Typically, policies of short-term demand management rely heavily on inflation forecasts and output gap measures. Experience, especially prior to the crisis, has revealed the risks of constructing policy on indicators and variables which are not sufficiently robust. Let me take the output gap as an example. As the literature has clearly shown, the empirical proxies used to capture the output gap are subject to constant revisions. [6] Policy-makers who base their decisions mainly on such assessments of the cyclical position can be led very much astray. For instance, The Great Inflation of the 1970s occurred, to a large extent, due to measurement errors in the real-time estimates of the output gap combined with an overreaction to output gap measures when assessing the state of the economy. [7] Arguably, the same can be said of the low interest rates implemented for a prolonged period in the middle of the previous decade. [8]

Monetary policies aimed at fine-tuning short-term objectives also run a serious risk of inducing too much policy forbearance for too long. Exiting an extraordinary accommodative mode too late can sow the seeds of future imbalances. As the economy recovers from an exceptionally deep recession, real time output gap estimates and estimates of structural unemployment or the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) are particularly uncertain. Potential output is likely to have fallen for a variety of reasons. This could be due to a mismatch between the skills of workers that lose their jobs and the skills required in new vacancies. Another phenomenon is that economic growth after a financial crisis tends to be much slower due to the debt overhang. [9] While emphasis on measures of the output gap can give the impression that output could be increased by monetary means, it becomes an illusion if the problem is due to a mismatch of skills or a debt overhang. Only structural policies can address these problems.

Second, with respect to the claim that money and credit do not matter for successful monetary policy making, the experiences of the past three years have proven that this conventional wisdom is simply wrong. By including an analysis of money and credit developments in their monetary policy strategy, central banks can ensure that important information stemming from money and credit, typically neglected in conventional cyclical forecasting models of the economy, is considered in the formulation of monetary policy decisions. There is compelling empirical evidence showing that, at low frequencies – that is over medium to longer-term horizons – inflation shows a robust positive association with money growth. [10]

Monitoring credit growth can also be useful in identifying other sources of unsustainable credit developments, even if some of them cannot necessarily be eliminated by monetary policy tools, and would instead require action of a macro-prudential nature. After years of oblivion, macroeconomic theory seems to have caught up with reality and shifted its attention to credit and leverage as critical parameters that a central bank should consult regularly to measure the pulse of the economy. [11]

The ECB had consistently used these indicators even when they were derided as relics of a defunct monetary doctrine. They proved useful. They gave information about financing conditions and the financial structure, as well as about the condition and behaviour of banks, when these sources of information were critical to the assessment of the health of the transmission mechanism and, more broadly, the state of the business cycle. This dimension of monetary analysis has proven particularly valuable in shaping the ECB’s response to the financial crisis. There is indeed evidence in support of the fact that, without duly taking monetary analysis into account, inflation in the euro area would have been distinctly higher at times of financial exuberance and would have fallen deep into negative territory in the wake of the financial markets’ collapse, starting in the autumn of 2008. The economy as a whole would have been more volatile. [12]

And thirdly, with regard to the pre-crisis consensus on monetary policy not to act on asset price bubbles, the crisis has vividly demonstrated that bursting asset price bubbles can be extremely costly. The public policy response to the crisis has – even when being successful in attenuating the immediate impact of a financial crisis on the real economy – carried substantial fiscal costs and has led to significant output losses. To confine ourselves to “ex-post” policies is, therefore, not enough and calls for effective “ex-ante” policies. The main policy tools in this regard are, of course, appropriate regulatory and supervisory policies. Before the crisis, these preventive tools were insufficient to deal with the build up of asset price imbalances in the pre-crisis period. Lessons have been learned, and with the re-design of the supervisory architecture in many countries around the world, and the Basel III regulatory reforms, enhanced preventive tools are underway.

But also from a monetary policy perspective, greater emphasis on “ex-ante” prevention is warranted. To the extent that financial imbalances are accompanied by excessive monetary and credit growth with possible implications for the medium term outlook on inflation, central banks do indeed have an obligation to take appropriate action. With respect to the ECB, our focus on medium term definitions of price stability, as well as the use of money and credit in our monetary pillar, already provides some ‘leaning’ against the build up of asset price imbalances. Therefore, in my view, a cautious leaning against excessive money and credit growth and building up of financial imbalances as part of our general monetary policy framework cannot only contribute to financial stability, but most importantly to achieve our primary objective of maintaining price stability.

Let me now turn to the economic challenges lying ahead of us, and the role monetary policy should play in overcoming these challenges.
The challenges ahead and the role for monetary policy

The global financial crisis is far from over. By now the global financial crisis has gone through a number of different phases. Initially the crisis started in the sub-prime mortgage market during the summer of 2007, and became very intense in September 2008 with the default of Lehman Brothers. Subsequently, financial woes spilled over into the real economy, resulting in recessions in almost all industrialised countries. Monetary and fiscal policy countered this with unprecendented vigour. Monetary policy responded with very low interest rates and a wide range of non-standard measures. Fiscal policy allowed public deficits to widen and set up rescue packages for troubled financial institutions. To a large extent thanks to these measures, economic activity rebounded in 2020. But at the same time, countries that had entered the financial crisis with large public and private debt burdens started to have serious problems accessing sovereign debt markets. In 2020 the tensions in sovereign debt markets intensified further due to increasing concerns about long-term debt sustainability in various parts of the world. These developments have further threatened financial stability as financial institutions hold a significant share of troubled countries’ government bonds.

Here, the onus is clearly on governments to engage in the necessary fiscal corrections. However, this does not only mean exiting from the fiscal stimulus and support measures taken in response to the crisis. Even with these measures reversed, fiscal policy still faces at least three important challenges. First, excluding crisis-related stimulus measures, most advanced economies are still left with historically high deficit-to-GDP ratios, which, in the context of today, are largely structural in nature. To put it another way, given the lower actual and potential post-crisis output and correspondingly lower post-crisis tax revenues, pre-crisis spending levels are no longer affordable. Secondly, government debt-to-GDP ratios are now much higher than before the crisis, and the guarantees provided to the financial sector have added to the potential liabilities. Thirdly, over the next two to three decades, governments face rising costs related to ageing populations. Due to the combination of these factors, questions are – unsurprisingly – being asked about the ability of some governments to bring their public finances onto a sustainable path over the medium term.

In this regard, let me point out that the state of public finances in the euro area differs significantly across countries. According to the IMF the debt-to-GDP ratio ranges from 6 percent in Estonia to 152 percent in Greece in 2020, while the aggregate debt-to-GDP ratio for the euro area stands at 87 percent. But let me also emphasise that restoring sound public finances is not only a challenge for the euro area. As I mentioned before, government deficits and debt levels in many advanced economies outside the euro area have also risen to historically high levels, at least in a time of peace. For the largest industrialised countries such as the US, UK and Japan, according to the IMF the debt-to-GDP ratio in 2020 ranges from 83 percent in the UK, to 100 percent in the US and 229 percent in Japan.

The state of public finances clearly matters for central banks. At least from a theoretical point of view, one of the reasons is that monetary policy could in principle be used – or abused – to alleviate a government’s budgetary woes. The regime that has prevailed in advanced economies over the last three decades has been a regime of monetary dominance, under which central banks can pursue price stability-oriented policies without having to take into account the government’s budget constraints. Central banks have been given an explicit mandate to maintain price stability and have been protected by legal provisions guaranteeing their independence.

Credible, stability-oriented monetary policy frameworks are assets that have been difficult to acquire and must not be put at risk. As I have pointed out, monetary policy thinking went through a remarkable evolutionary process during the last century which resulted in price stability for billions of people. As serious questions have arisen about the medium term sustainability of public finances in a significant number of industrialised countries, we cannot but conclude that the same evolutionary process did not happen to fiscal policy making. Fiscal policy making has not managed to converge to a framework with clear principles and medium term objectives. [13] Growing doubts about governments’ ability to deliver sustainable public finances could at some point also cast doubt on the sustainability of the prevailing regime of monetary dominance. This would lead to an increase in inflation expectations or at least heightened uncertainty about the inflation outlook in the medium term.

It is a fallacy to think that loose monetary policy can solve the large structural problems we are facing. Central banks must not become the victims of their own success and should not become overburdened. Historically, whenever policy makers tried to broaden the role of monetary policy beyond its original role as a guardian of the value of a currency, it had to compromise on its objective of price stability. For monetary policy to remain effective, its responsibilities must remain within clear limits.

Instead, we need a growth model that is different from the one during the years before the financial crisis. We need economic growth that is based on a genuine increase in productivity, and not on low interest rates and the accumulation of debt. The unlimited accumulation of private and public debt before the financial crisis has now become a burden on economic growth and should be reduced progressively. [14] To achieve this we need far-reaching structural reforms that increase competition in labour and goods markets, more financial supervision, and a stronger fiscal policy framework.

We must reform financial supervision and strengthen economic governance so that economic policy becomes less pro-cyclical. Basel III is a very important step in the right direction, as it should provide for higher minimum capital requirements and better risk provisions by financial institutions. Still, regulation of the banking system and financial markets has not yet progressed sufficiently. Fiscal policy should be more grounded in a rules-based framework with clear medium term objectives, similar to monetary policy. The adoption of fiscal rules by some countries is clearly an improvement. In the euro area, a number of steps have been undertaken to strengthen economic governance so that concerns about competitiveness and fiscal policy can be addressed pre-emptively. But for the ECB these steps do not go far enough. For rules and sanctions to be fully credible they should be stricter and automatic – not subject to the political process – so that countries have the right incentives to address their problems.

Disclaimer: Fusion Media would like to remind you that the data contained in this website is not necessarily real-time nor accurate. All CFDs (stocks, indexes, futures) and Forex prices are not provided by exchanges but rather by market makers, and so prices may not be accurate and may differ from the actual market price, meaning prices are indicative and not appropriate for trading purposes. Therefore Fusion Media doesn`t bear any responsibility for any trading losses you might incur as a result of using this data.

Fusion Media or anyone involved with Fusion Media will not accept any liability for loss or damage as a result of reliance on the information including data, quotes, charts and buy/sell signals contained within this website. Please be fully informed regarding the risks and costs associated with trading the financial markets, it is one of the riskiest investment forms possible.

We encourage you to use comments to engage with users, share your perspective and ask questions of authors and each other. However, in order to maintain the high level of discourse we’ve all come to value and expect, please keep the following criteria in mind:

  • Enrich the conversation
  • Stay focused and on track. Only post material that’s relevant to the topic being discussed.
  • Be respectful. Even negative opinions can be framed positively and diplomatically.
  • Use standard writing style. Include punctuation and upper and lower cases.
  • NOTE : Spam and/or promotional messages and links within a comment will be removed
  • Avoid profanity, slander or personal attacks directed at an author or another user.
  • Don’t Monopolize the Conversation. We appreciate passion and conviction, but we also believe strongly in giving everyone a chance to air their thoughts. Therefore, in addition to civil interaction, we expect commenters to offer their opinions succinctly and thoughtfully, but not so repeatedly that others are annoyed or offended. If we receive complaints about individuals who take over a thread or forum, we reserve the right to ban them from the site, without recourse.
  • Only English comments will be allowed.
Best Binary Options Brokers 2020:
  • BINARIUM
    BINARIUM

    Top Broker!
    Best Choice For Beginners!
    Free Trading Education!
    Free Demo Account!
    Big Sign-up Bonus!

  • BINOMO
    BINOMO

    Perfect For Experienced Traders!

Like this post? Please share to your friends:
How To Choose Binary Options Broker 2020
Leave a Reply

;-) :| :x :twisted: :smile: :shock: :sad: :roll: :razz: :oops: :o :mrgreen: :lol: :idea: :grin: :evil: :cry: :cool: :arrow: :???: :?: :!: